Main Article Content

David Peón
Universidade da Coruña
Spain
Manel Antelo
Universidade de Santiago de Compostela
Spain
Anxo Calvo-Silvosa
Universidade da Coruña
Spain
Vol. 6 No. 1 (2017), Articles, pages 24-58
DOI: https://doi.org/10.17979/ejge.2017.6.1.4322
Submitted: Sep 24, 2018 Published: Jul 7, 2017
How to Cite

Abstract

This paper overviews the theoretical and empirical research on behavioral biases and their influence in the literature. To provide a systematic exposition, we present a unified framework that takes the reader through an original taxonomy, based on the reviews of relevant authors in the field. In particular, we establish three broad categories that may be distinguished: heuristics and biases; choices, values and frames; and social factors. We then describe the main biases within each category, and revise the main theoretical and empirical developments, linking each bias with other biases and anomalies that are related to them, according to the literature.

Downloads

Download data is not yet available.

Article Details

References

Ackert, L.F., B.K. Church, J. Tompkins & P. Zhang (2005). What's in a name? An experimental examination of investment behavior. Review of Finance 9, 281-304. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10679-005-7594-2

Adam, M.T.P. & E.B. Kroll (2012). Physiological evidence of attraction to chance. Journal of Neuroscience, Psychology and Economics 5(3), 152-165. https://doi.org/10.1037/a0029513

Ahern, K.R., D. Daminelli & C. Fracassi (2015). Lost in translation? The effect of cultural values on mergers around the world. Journal of Financial Economics 117, 165-189. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2012.08.006

Akerlof, G.A. & R.J. Shiller (2009). How animal spirits destabilize economies. McKinsey Quarterly 3, 127-135.

Alary, D., C. Gollier & N. Treich (2013). The effect of ambiguity aversion on insurance and self-protection. The Economic Journal 123, 1188-1202. https://doi.org/10.1111/ecoj.12035

Alós-Ferrer, C. & S. Hügelschäfer (2012). Faith in intuition and behavioral biases. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 84, 182-192. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jebo.2012.08.004

Altman, M. (2012). Implications of behavioural economics for financial literacy and public policy. The Journal of Socio-Economics 41, 677-690. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.socec.2012.06.002

Andersen, S., G.W. Harrison, M.I. Lau & E.I. Rutström (2008). Eliciting risk and time preferences. Econometrica 76(3), 583–618. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-0262.2008.00848.x

Andersen, S., G.W. Harrison, M.I. Lau & E.I. Rutström (2014). Discounting behavior: A reconsideration. European Economic Review 71, 15-33. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.euroecorev.2014.06.009

Aral, S. & D. Walker (2014). Tie strength, embeddedness, and social influence: A large-scale networked experiment. Management Science 60(6), 1352-70. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.2014.1936

Argyle, M. (1991). Cooperation: The basis of sociability. Routledge.

Ariely, D., A. Bracha & S. Meier (2009). Doing good or doing well? Image motivation and monetary incentives in behaving prosocially. The American Economic Review 99(1), 544-555. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.99.1.544

Arkes, H.R., D. Hirshleifer, D. Jiang & S.S. Lim (2008). Reference point adaptation: Tests in the domain of security trading. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 105, 67–81. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.obhdp.2007.04.005

Arkes, H.R., D. Hirshleifer, D. Jiang & S.S. Lim (2010). A cross-cultural study of reference point adaptation: Evidence from China, Korea and the US. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 112(2), 99-111. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.obhdp.2010.02.002

Asch, S.E. (1952). Social Psychology. Prentice Hall. https://doi.org/10.1037/10025-000

Ball, R., S.P. Kothari & V.V. Nikolaev (2013). Econometrics of the Basu asymmetric timeliness coefficient and accounting conservatism. Journal of Accounting Research 51(5), 1071-97. https://doi.org/10.1111/1475-679X.12026

Ball, S. & C. Eckel (1998). The economic value of status. Journal of Socio-Economics 27(4), 495-514. https://doi.org/10.1016/S1053-5357(98)80004-8

Ball, S., C. Eckel, P.J. Grossman & W. Zane (2001). Status in markets. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 116(1), 161-188. https://doi.org/10.1162/003355301556374

Bao, Y., Z. Gao, M. Xu, H. Sun, & H. Yang (2015). Travel mental budgeting under road toll: An investigation based on user equilibrium. Transportation Research Part A 73, 1-17. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.tra.2014.12.010

Barber, B.M. & T. Odean (2008). All that glitters: The effect of attention and news on the buying behavior of individual and institutional investors. Review of Financial Studies 21(2), 785-818. https://doi.org/10.1093/rfs/hhm079

Barberis, N.C. (2013). Thirty years of prospect theory in Economics: A review and assessment. The Journal of Economic Perspectives 27(1), 173-195. https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.27.1.173

Barberis, N.C. & M. Huang (2007). The loss aversion/narrow framing approach to the equity premium puzzle. In R. Mehra (ed.) Handbook of Investments: Equity Premium, North-Holland, Amsterdam, pp. 199–229.

Barberis, N.C. & M. Huang (2009). Preferences with frames: A new utility specification that allows for the framing of risks. Journal of Economics Dynamics and Control 33(8), 1555-76. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jedc.2009.01.009

Barberis, N.C. & R.H. Thaler (2003). A survey of Behavioral Finance. In G.M. Constantinides, M. Harris and R.M. Stulz (eds.), Handbook of the Economics of Finance 1(1), 1053-1128.

Bar-Hillel, M. (1973). On the subjective probability of compound events. Organizational Behavior and Human Performance 9, 396-406. https://doi.org/10.1016/0030-5073(73)90061-5

Battalio, R.H., A. Lerman, J. Livnat & R.R. Mendenhall (2012). Who, if anyone, reacts to accrual information? Journal of Accounting and Economics 53, 205-224. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jacceco.2011.06.007

Baucells, M., M. Weber & F. Welfens (2011). Reference point formation and updating: Theory and experiments. Journal Management Science 57(3), 506-519. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.1100.1286

Bem, D.J. (1965). An experimental analysis of self-persuasion. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology 1, 199-218. https://doi.org/10.1016/0022-1031(65)90026-0

Benartzi, S. & R.H. Thaler (1995). Myopic loss aversion and the equity premium puzzle. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 110(1), 73-92. https://doi.org/10.2307/2118511

Benartzi, S. & R.H. Thaler (1999). Risk aversion or myopia? Choices in repeated gambles and retirement investments. Management Science 45(3), 364-381. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.45.3.364

Beugelsdijk, S. & B. Frijns (2010). A cultural explanation of the foreign bias in international asset allocation. Journal of Banking and Finance 34, 2121-31. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbankfin.2010.01.020

Bikhchandani, S., D. Hirshleifer & I. Welch (1998). Learning from the behavior of others: Conformity, fads, and informational cascades. The Journal of Economic Perspectives 12(3), 151-170. https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.12.3.151

Bloom, N., R. Sadun & J. van Reenen (2015). The organization of firms across countries. Quarterly Journal of Economics 127(4), 1663-1705. https://doi.org/10.1093/qje/qje029

Bolton, G.E. & A. Ockenfels (2000). ERC: A theory of equity, reciprocity, and competition. American Economic Review 90(1), 166-193. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.90.1.166

Bordalo, P., N. Gennaioli & A. Shleifer (2012). Salience theory of choice under risk. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 127(3), 1243-85. https://doi.org/10.1093/qje/qjs018

Bordalo, P., N. Gennaioli & A. Shleifer (2013). Salience and consumer choice. Journal of Political Economy 121(5), 803-843. https://doi.org/10.1086/673885

Boyle, P., L. Garlappi, R. Uppal & T. Wang (2012). Keynes meets Markowitz: The trade-off between familiarity and diversification. Management Science 58(2), 253-272. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.1110.1349

Bracha, A. & D.J. Brown (2012). Affective decision making: A theory of optimism bias. Games and Economic Behavior 75, 67-80. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.geb.2011.11.004

Briley, D.A., L.J. Shrum & R.S. Wyer (2013). Factors affecting judgments of prevalence and representation: Implications for public policy and marketing. Journal of Public Policy and Marketing 32, 112-118. https://doi.org/10.1509/jppm.12.045

Burger, N., G. Charness & J. Lynham (2011). Field and online experiments on self-control. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 77, 393-404. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jebo.2010.11.010

Burnside, C., B. Han, D. Hirshleifer & T.Y. Wang (2011). Investor overconfidence and the forward premium puzzle. Review of Economic Studies 78, 523-558. https://doi.org/10.1093/restud/rdq013

Calvillo, D.P. (2014). Individual differences in susceptibility to misinformation effects and hindsight bias. Journal of General Psychology 141(4), 393-407. https://doi.org/10.1080/00221309.2014.954917

Camerer, C.F. & D. Lovallo (1999). Overconfidence and excess entry: An experimental approach. The American Economic Review 89(1), 306-318. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.89.1.306

Camerer, C.F. & G. Loewenstein (2004). Behavioral Economics: Past, present, future. In C.F. Camerer, G. Loewenstein and M. Rabin (eds.), Advances in Behavioral Economics, Princeton University Press, 3-51.

Camerer, C.F. & R.H. Thaler (1995). Anomalies: Ultimatums, dictators and manners. Journal of Economic Perspectives 9(2), 209-219. https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.9.2.209

Cao, H.H., B. Han, D. Hirshleifer & H.H. Zhang (2011). Fear of the unknown: Familiarity and economic decisions. Review of Finance 15(19), 173-206. https://doi.org/10.1093/rof/rfp023

Carlsson, F. & P. Martinsson (2008). How much is too much? An investigation of the effect of the number of choice sets, context dependence and the choice of bid vectors in choice experiments. Environmental and Resource Economics 40, 165-176. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-007-9146-z

Carpenter, J. & C.K. Myers (2010). Why volunteer? Evidence on the role of altruism, image, and incentives. Journal of Public Economics 94, 911-920. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jpubeco.2010.07.007

Cason, T.N. & C.R. Plott (2014). Misconceptions and game form recognition: Challenges to theories of revealed preference and framing. Journal of Political Economy 122(6), 1235-70. https://doi.org/10.1086/677254

Cesarini, D., M. Johannesson, P.K.E. Magnusson & B. Wallace (2012). The behavioral genetics of behavioral anomalies. Management Science 58(1), 21-34. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.1110.1329

Chan, L.K.C., N. Jegadeesh and J. Lakonishok (1996). Momentum strategies. The Journal of Finance 51(5), 1681-1713. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.1996.tb05222.x

Chelley-Steeley, P.L., B.D. Kluger & J.M. Steeley (2015). Earnings and hindsight bias: An experimental study. Economic Letters 134, 130-132. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econlet.2015.07.005

Chen, G., K.A. Kim, J.R. Nofsinger & O.M. Rui (2007). Trading performance, disposition effect, overconfidence, representativeness bias, and experience of emerging market investors. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making 20(4), 425-451. https://doi.org/10.1002/bdm.561

Chen, L., A.G. Kök & J.D. Tong (2013). The effect of payment schemes on inventory decisions: The role of mental accounting. Management Science 59(2), 436-451. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.1120.1638

Chew, S.H., R.P. Ebstein & S. Zhong (2012). Ambiguity aversion and familiarity bias: Evidence from behavioral and gene association studies. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 44, 1-18. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11166-011-9134-0

Chou, H.G. & N. Edge (2012). "They are happier and having better lives than I am'': The impact of using Facebook on perceptions of others' lives. Cyberpsychology, behavior, and social networking 15(2), 117-121. https://doi.org/10.1089/cyber.2011.0324

Cohn, A., Engelmann, J., Fehr, E., & Maréchal, M.A. (2015). Evidence for countercyclical risk aversion: An experiment with financial professionals. American Economic Review 105(2), 860-885. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.20131314

Cokely, E.T. & C.M. Kelley (2009). Cognitive abilities and superior decision making under risk: A protocol analysis and process model evaluation. Judgmental Decision Making 4, 20–33.

Cooper, J.C. & W.E. Kovacic (2012). Behavioral economics: implications for regulatory behavior. Journal of Regulatory Economics 41, 41–58. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11149-011-9180-1

Cornelissen, J.P. & M.D. Werner (2014). Putting framing in perspective: A review of framing and frame analysis across the management and organizational literature. The Academy of Management Annals 8(1), 181-235. https://doi.org/10.1080/19416520.2014.875669

Cosmides, L. & J. Tooby (1990). Is the mind a frequentist? Second Annual Meeting of the Human Behavior and Evolution Society, LA, CA. Cited in G. Gigerenzer (1991), How to make cognitive illusions disappear: Beyond 'heuristics and biases', In W. Stroebe and M. Hewstone (eds.), European Review of Social Psychology, Wiley.

Cowley, E., D.A. Briley & C. Farrell (2015). How do gamblers maintain an illusion of control? Journal of Business Research 68, 2181-88. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbusres.2015.03.018

Cready, W., Kumas, A., & Subasi, M. (2014). Are trade size-based inferences about traders reliable? Evidence from institutional earnings-related trading. Journal of Accounting Research 52(4), 877-909. https://doi.org/10.1111/1475-679X.12056

Croskerry, P., G. Singhal & S. Mamede (2013). Cognitive debiasing 1: Origins of bias and theory of debiasing. BMJ Quality and Safety 22(2), 58-64. https://doi.org/10.1136/bmjqs-2012-001712

Daniel, K., Hirshleifer, D., & Teoh, S.H. (2002). Investor psychology in capital markets: evidence and policy implications. Journal of Monetary Economics 49, 139-209. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0304-3932(01)00091-5

Daniel, K., Hirshleifer, D., & Subrahmanyam, A. (1998). Investor psychology and security market under- and overreactions. The Journal of Finance 53(6), 1839-85. https://doi.org/10.1111/0022-1082.00077

Das, S., H. Markowitz, J. Scheid & M. Statman (2010). Portfolio optimization with mental accounts. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 45(2), 311-334. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0022109010000141

De Giorgi, E.G. & S. Legg (2012). Dynamic portfolio choice and asset pricing with narrow framing and probability weighting. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 36, 951-972. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jedc.2012.01.010

DellaVigna, S. (2009). Psychology and Economics: Evidence from the field. Journal of Economic Literature 47(2), 315-372. https://doi.org/10.1257/jel.47.2.315

Duong, C., G. Pescetto & D. Santamaria (2014). How value-glamour investors use financial information: UK evidence of investors' confirmation bias. The European Journal of Finance 20(6), 524-549. https://doi.org/10.1080/1351847X.2012.722117

Durante, R., L. Putterman & J. van der Weele (2014). Preferences for redistribution and perception of fairness: An experimental study. Journal of the European Economic Association 12(4), 1059-1086. https://doi.org/10.1111/jeea.12082

Einhorn, H.J. & R.M. Hogarth (1978). Confidence in judgment: Persistence of the illusion of validity. Psychological Review 85(5), 395-416. https://doi.org/10.1037/0033-295X.85.5.395

Einhorn, H.J. & R.M. Hogarth (1986). Decision making under ambiguity. Journal of Business 59(4), Part 2: The Behavioral Foundations of Economic Theory, S225-S250.

Ent, M.R. & R.F. Baumeister (2014). Obedience, self-control, and the voice of culture. Journal of Social Issues 70(3), 574-586. https://doi.org/10.1111/josi.12079

Epley, N. & T. Gilovich (2001). Putting adjustment back in the anchoring and adjustment heuristic: Differential processing of self-generated and experimenter-provided anchors. Psychological Science 12, 391-396. https://doi.org/10.1111/1467-9280.00372

Epley, N. & T. Gilovich (2006). The anchoring-and-adjustment heuristic: Why the adjustments are insufficient. Psychological Science 17(4), 311-318. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9280.2006.01704.x

Epley, N. & T. Gilovich (2010). Anchoring unbound. Journal of Consumer Psychology 20(1), 20-24. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jcps.2009.12.005

Erceg, N. & Z. Galic (2014). Overconfidence bias and conjunction fallacy in predicting outcomes of football matches. Journal of Economic Psychology 42, 52-62. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.joep.2013.12.003

Erev, I., T.S. Wallsten & D.V. Budescu (1994). Simultaneous over- and underconfidence: The role of error in judgment processes. Psychological Review 10(3), 519-527. https://doi.org/10.1037/0033-295X.101.3.519

Etner, J., M. Jeleva & J.-M. Tallon (2012). Decision theory under ambiguity. Journal of Economic Surveys 26(2), 234-270. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-6419.2010.00641.x

Fellner, G. & M. Sutter (2009). Causes, consequences, and cures of myopic loss aversion: An experimental investigation. The Economic Journal 119, 900-916. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-0297.2009.02251.x

Fellner, W. (1961). Distortion of subjective probabilities as a reaction to uncertainty. Quarterly Journal of Economics 75, 670-690. https://doi.org/10.2307/1884325

Festinger, L. (1957). A Theory of Cognitive Dissonance. Stanford University Press.

Finucane, M.L., A. Alhakami, P. Slovic & S.M. Johnson (2000). The affect heuristic in judgments of risks and benefits. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making 13(1), 1-17. https://doi.org/10.1002/(SICI)1099-0771(200001/03)13:1<1::AID-BDM333>3.0.CO;2-S

Fischhoff, B. (1982). For those condemned to study the past: Heuristics and biases in hindsight. In D. Kahneman, P. Slovic and A. Tversky, Judgment under uncertainty: Heuristics and biases. Cambridge University Press. https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511809477.024

Frankel, J. & J. Schreger (2013). Over-optimistic official forecasts and fiscal rules in the Eurozone. Review of World Economics 149, 247-272. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10290-013-0150-9

Frankfurter, G.M., E.G. McGoun & D.E. Allen (2004). The prescriptive turn in Behavioral Finance. Journal of Socio-Economics 33, 449-468. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.socec.2004.04.006

Frederick, S., D. Kahneman & D. Mochon (2010). Elaborating a simpler theory of anchoring. Journal of Consumer Psychology 20, 17-19. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jcps.2009.12.004

Frederick, S., G. Loewenstein & T. O'Donoghe (2002). Time discounting and time preference: A critical review. Journal of Economic Literature 40, 351-401. https://doi.org/10.1257/jel.40.2.351

Füllbrunn, S., H.A. Rau & U. Weitzel (2014). Does ambiguity aversion survive in experimental asset markets? Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 107, 810-826. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jebo.2014.03.013

Furnham, A. & H.C. Boo (2011). A literature review on the anchoring effect. The Journal of Socio-Economics 40, 35-42. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.socec.2010.10.008

Gatherwood, J. & J. Weber (2014). Self-control, financial literacy and the co-holding puzzle. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 107, 455-469. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jebo.2014.04.018

Gennaioli, N. & A. Shleifer (2010). What comes to mind. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 125(4), 1399-1433. https://doi.org/10.1162/qjec.2010.125.4.1399

Gigerenzer, G. (1991). How to make cognitive illusions disappear: Beyond 'heuristics and biases'. In W. Stroebe & M. Hewstone (eds.), European Review of Social Psychology, Wiley. https://doi.org/10.1080/14792779143000033

Gigerenzer, G. & D.G. Goldstein (2011). The recognition heuristic: A decade of research. Judgment and Decision Making 6(1), 100-121.

Gigerenzer, G. & W. Gaissmaier (2011). Heuristic decision making. Annual Review of Psychology 62, 451-482. https://doi.org/10.1146/annurev-psych-120709-145346

Gigerenzer, G., U. Hoffrage & H. Kleinbölting (1991). Probabilistic mental models: A Brunswikian theory of confidence. Psychological Review 98, 506–528. https://doi.org/10.1037/0033-295X.98.4.506

Gilbert, P., J. Price & S. Allan (1995). Social comparison, social attractiveness and evolution: How might they be related? New Ideas in Psychology 13(2), 149-165. https://doi.org/10.1016/0732-118X(95)00002-X

Givoni, M., J. Macmillen, D. Banister, & E. Feitelson (2013), From Policy Measures to Policy Packages. Transport Reviews 33(1), 1-20. https://doi.org/10.1080/01441647.2012.744779

Gneezy, U., A. Kapteyn & J. Potters (2003). Evaluation periods and asset prices in a market experiment. Journal of Finance 58, 821–837. https://doi.org/10.1111/1540-6261.00547

Goldstein, D.G. & G. Gigerenzer (1999). The recognition heuristic: How ignorance makes us smart. In G. Gigerenzer, P.M. Todd, and the ABC Research Group, Simple heuristics that make us smart, New York: Oxford University Press, pp. 37–58.

Goldstein, D.G. & G. Gigerenzer (2002). Models of ecological rationality: The recognition heuristic. Psychological Review 109, 75–90. https://doi.org/10.1037/0033-295X.109.1.75

Griffin, D. & A. Tversky (1992). The weighing of evidence and the determinants of confidence. Cognitive Psychology 24(3), 411-435. https://doi.org/10.1016/0010-0285(92)90013-R

Griffin, D.W., R. Gonzalez, D.J. Koehler & T. Gilovich (2012). Judgmental heuristics: A historical overview. In K.J. Holyoak & R.G. Morrison (eds.), The Oxford Handbook of Thinking and Reasoning, Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 322-345. https://doi.org/10.1093/oxfordhb/9780199734689.013.0017

Griffith, R.M. (1949). Odds adjustments by American horse-race bettors. The American Journal of Psychology 62(2), 290-294. https://doi.org/10.2307/1418469

Grinblatt, M. & M. Keloharju (2009). Sensation seeking, overconfidence and trading activity. The Journal of Finance 64(2), 549-578. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.2009.01443.x

Guiso, L., P. Sapienza & L. Zingales (2006). Does culture affect economic outcomes? Journal of Economic Perspectives 20(2), 23-48. https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.20.2.23

Güth, W., R. Schmittberger & B. Schwarze (1982). An experimental analysis of ultimatum bargaining. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 3, 367-388. https://doi.org/10.1016/0167-2681(82)90011-7

Haack, P., M.D. Pfarrer & A.G. Scherer (2014). Legitimacy-as-feeling: How affect leads to vertical legitimacy spillovers in transnational governance. Journal of Management Studies 51(4), 634-666. https://doi.org/10.1111/joms.12071

Haisley, E., R. Mostafa & G. Loewenstein (2008). Myopic risk-seeking: The impact of narrow decision bracketing on lottery play. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 37, 57-75. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11166-008-9041-1

Hardin, A.M. & C.A. Looney (2012). Myopic loss aversion: Demystifying the key factors influencing decision problem framing. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 117, 311-331. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.obhdp.2011.11.005

Heath, C., R.P. Larrick & J. Klayman (1998). Cognitive repairs: How organizational practices can compensate for individual shortcomings. Research in Organizational Behavior 20, 1-37.

Henrich, J., R. Boyd, S. Bowles, C. Camerer, H. Gintis, R. McElreath & E. Fehr (2001). In search of Homo economicus: Behavioral experiments in 15 small-scale societies. American Economic Review 91(2), 73-79. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.91.2.73

Hens, T. & K. Bachmann (2008). Behavioral Finance for Private Banking. John Wiley and Sons.

Hirshleifer, D. (2008). Psychological bias as a driver of financial regulation. European Financial Management 14(5), 856-874. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-036X.2007.00437.x

Hirshleifer, D. (2015). Behavioral Finance. Annual Review of Financial Economics 7(7), 133-159. https://doi.org/10.1146/annurev-financial-092214-043752

Hirshleifer, D. & S.H. Teoh (2003). Limited attention, information disclosure and financial reporting. Journal of Accounting and Economics 36(1), 337-386. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jacceco.2003.10.002

Hodges, S.H., R.G. Tompkins & W.T. Ziemba (2008). The favorite longshot bias in SandP 500 and FTSE 100 Index futures options: The return to bets and the cost of insurance. In Handbook of Sports and Lottery Markets, Elsevier.

Hoff, K. & P. Priyanka (2004). Belief systems and durable inequalities: An experimental investigation of Indian caste. World Bank Working Paper 3351. https://doi.org/10.1596/1813-9450-3351

Hoffrage, U., R. Hertwig & G. Gigerenzer (2000). Hindsight bias: A by-product of knowledge updating? Journal of Experimental Psychology: Learning, Memory and Cognition 26(3), 566-581. https://doi.org/10.1037/0278-7393.26.3.566

Hossain, T. & J.A. List (2012). The behavioralist visits the factory: Increasing productivity using simple framing manipulations. Management Science 58(12), 2151-2167. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.1120.1544

Hu, Y. & X. Li (2011). Context-dependent product evaluations: An empirical analysis of internet book reviews. Journal of Interactive Marketing 25, 123-133. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.intmar.2010.10.001

Huber, J., M. Kirchler & T. Stöckl (2010). The hot hand belief and the gambler's fallacy in investment decisions under risk. Theory and Decision 68, 445-462. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11238-008-9106-2

Janis, I.L. (1972). Victims of Groupthink, Houghton Mifflin.

Jaspersen, J.G. & V. Aseervatham (2015). The influence of affect on heuristic thinking in insurance demand. The Journal of Risk and Insurance. https://doi.org/10.1111/jori.12088

Kahneman, D. (2003a). Maps of bounded rationality: Psychology for Behavioral Economics. The American Economic Review 93(5), 1449-75. https://doi.org/10.1257/000282803322655392

Kahneman, D. (2003b). A perspective on judgment and choice: Mapping bounded rationality. American Psychologist 58(9), 697-720. https://doi.org/10.1037/0003-066X.58.9.697

Kahneman, D. & A. Tversky (1979). Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica 47(2), 263-292. https://doi.org/10.2307/1914185

Kahneman, D. & A. Tversky (1984). Choices, values and frames. American Psychologist 39, 341-350. https://doi.org/10.1037/0003-066X.39.4.341

Kahneman, D. & D. Lovallo (1993). Timid choices and bold forecasts: A cognitive perspective on risk taking. Management Science 39(1), 17-31. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.39.1.17

Kahneman, D. & M. Riepe (1998). Aspects of investor psychology. Journal of Portfolio Management 24, 52-65. https://doi.org/10.3905/jpm.1998.409643

Kahneman, D. & S. Frederick (2002). Representativeness revisited: Attribute substitution in intuitive judgment. In T. Gilovich, D. Griffin & D. Kahneman (eds.), Heuristics and biases: The psychology of intuitive thought, Cambridge University Press, pp. 49-81. https://doi.org/10.1017/cbo9780511808098.004

Kahneman, D. & S. Frederick (2005). A model of heuristic judgment. In K.J. Holyoake & R.G. Morrison (eds.) The Cambridge Handbook of Thinking and Reasoning, Cambridge University Press.

Kahneman, D., J.L. Knetsch & R.H. Thaler (1986a). Fairness as a constraint on profit seeking: Entitlements in the market. American Economic Review 76(4), 728-741.

Kahneman, D., J.L. Knetsch & R.H. Thaler (1986b). Fairness and the assumptions of Economics. Journal of Business 59(4), S285-S300. https://doi.org/10.1086/296367

Kahneman, D., J.L. Knetsch & R.H. Thaler (1991). Anomalies: The endowment effect, loss aversion, and status quo bias. The Journal of Economic Perspectives 5(1), 193-206. https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.5.1.193

Kahneman, D., P. Slovic & A. Tversky (1982). Judgment Under Uncertainty: Heuristics and Biases. Cambridge University Press. https://doi.org/10.1017/cbo9780511809477

Katona, G. (1975). Psychological Economics. Elsevier.

Kirby, K.N. & R.J. Herrnstein (1995). Preference reversals due to myopic discounting of delayed reward. Psychology Science 6(2), 83-89. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9280.1995.tb00311.x

Knetsch, J.L. (1989). The endowment effect and evidence of nonreversible indifference curves. The American Economic Review 79(5), 1277-84.

Koch, A.K. & J. Nafzinger (2016). Goals and bracketing under mental accounting. Journal of Economic Theory 162, 305-361. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jet.2016.01.001

Koop, G.J. & J.G. Johnson (2012). The use of multiple reference points in risky decision making. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making 25, 49-62. https://doi.org/10.1002/bdm.713

Koriat, A., S. Lichtenstein & B. Fischhoff (1980). Reasons for confidence. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Human Learning and Memory 6(2), 107-118. https://doi.org/10.1037/0278-7393.6.2.107

Kõszegi, B. & M. Rabin (2006). A model of reference-dependent preferences. Quarterly Journal of Economics 121(4), 1133-65. https://doi.org/10.1093/qje/121.4.1133

Kuran, T. & C. Sunstein (1999). Availability cascades and risk regulation. Stanford Law Review 51, 683–768. https://doi.org/10.2307/1229439

Lacetera, N., D.G. Pope & J.R. Sydnor (2014). Heuristic thinking and limited attention in the car market. American Economic Review 102(5), 2206-2236. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.102.5.2206

Lahvicka, J. (2014). What causes the favourite-longshot bias? Further evidence from tennis. Applied Economic Letters 21(2), 90-92. https://doi.org/10.1080/13504851.2013.842628

Landman, J. & M. Manis (1983). Social cognition: Some historical and theoretical perspectives. Advances in Experimental Social Psychology 16, 49-123. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0065-2601(08)60394-9

Langer, E.J. (1975). The illusion of control. The Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 32, 311-328, Reprinted short version in D. Kahneman, P. Slovic & A. Tversky (1982), Judgment under uncertainty: Heuristics and biases, Cambridge University Press.

Langer, T. & M. Weber (2005). Myopic prospect theory vs. myopic loss aversion: How general is the phenomenon? Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 56, 25-38. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jebo.2003.01.005

Lee, C.J. & E.B. Andrade (2011). Fear, social projection, and financial decision making. Journal of Marketing Research 48, S121-S129. https://doi.org/10.1509/jmkr.48.SPL.S121

Lejarraga, T. & C. Gonzalez (2011). Effects of feedback and complexity on repeated decisions from description. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 116, 286-295. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.obhdp.2011.05.001

Levinson, J.D. & K. Peng (2007). Valuing cultural differences in Behavioral Economics. The ICFAI Journal of Behavioral Finance 4(1), 32-47.

Libby, R. & K. Rennekamp (2012). Self-serving attribution bias, overconfidence, and the issuance of management forecasts. Journal of Accounting Research 50(1), 197-231. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1475-679X.2011.00430.x

Liberali, J.M., V.F. Reyna, S. Furlan, L.S. Stein & S.T. Pardo (2012). Individual differences in numeracy and cognitive reflection, with implications for biases and fallacies in probability judgments. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making 25, 361-381. https://doi.org/10.1002/bdm.752

List, J.A. (2007). On the interpretation of giving in dictator games. Journal of Political Economy 115(3), 482-493. https://doi.org/10.1086/519249

Liu, H. & A. M. Colman (2009). Ambiguity aversion in the long run: Repeated decisions under risk and uncertainty. Journal of Economic Psychology 30, 277-284. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.joep.2009.02.001

Lo, A.W., D.V. Repin & B.N. Steenbarger (2005). Fear and greed in financial markets: A clinical study of day-traders. The American Economic Review 95(2), 352-359. https://doi.org/10.1257/000282805774670095

Loewenstein, G. (1996). Out of control: Visceral influences on behavior. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 65(3), 272-292. https://doi.org/10.1006/obhd.1996.0028

Loewenstein, G., E.U. Weber, C.K. Hsee & N. Welch (2001). Risk as feelings. Psychological Bulletin 127(2), 267-86. https://doi.org/10.1037/0033-2909.127.2.267

Loewenstein, G., T. O'Donoghue & M. Rabin (2003). Projection bias in predicting future utility. Quarterly Journal of Economics 118(4), 1209-48. https://doi.org/10.1162/003355303322552784

Lovallo, D. & D. Kahneman (2003). Delusions of success: How optimism undermines executives' decisions. Harvard Business Review 81(7), 56-63.

Lunenburg, F.C. (2010). Group decision making: The potential for groupthink. International Journal of Management, Business, and Administration 13(1), 1-6.

Lupton, D. (2013). Risk and emotion: towards an alternative theoretical perspective. Health, Risk and Society 15(8), 634-647 https://doi.org/10.1080/13698575.2013.848847

Malmendier, U. & G. Tate (2005). CEO overconfidence and corporate investment. Journal of Finance 60(6), 2661-2700. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.2005.00813.x

Manski, C. (2000). Economic analysis of social interactions. Journal of Economic Perspectives 14(3), 115-136. https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.14.3.115

Marewski, J.N., W. Gaissmaier & G. Gigerenzer (2010). Good judgments do not require complex cognition. Cognitive Processing 11(2), 103-121. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10339-009-0337-0ç

Mayo-Wilson, C., K. Zollman & D. Danks (2012). Wisdom of crowds versus groupthink: learning in groups and in isolation. International Journal of Game Theory 42, 695-723. https://doi.org/10.1007/s00182-012-0329-7

McGraw, A.P., J.T. Larsen, D. Kahneman & D. Schkade (2010). Comparing gains and losses. Psychological Science 21(10), 1438-45. https://doi.org/10.1177/0956797610381504

Milgram, S. (1963). Behavioral study of obedience. The Journal of Abnormal and Social Psychology 67(4), 371-378. https://doi.org/10.1037/h0040525

Miller, J.G. (1984). Culture and the development of everyday social explanation. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 46, 961-978. https://doi.org/10.1037/0022-3514.46.5.961

Moore, D.A. & P.J. Healy (2008). The trouble with overconfidence. Psychological Review 115(2), 502–517. https://doi.org/10.1037/0033-295X.115.2.502

Mullainathan, S. & R.H. Thaler (2000). Behavioral Economics. MIT Dept. of Economics Working Paper No. 00-27. https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.245828

Nguyen, B. & P. Klaus (2013). Retail fairness: Exploring consumer perceptions of fairness towards retailers' marketing tactics. Journal of Retailing and Consumer Services 20, 311-324. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jretconser.2013.02.001

Nisbett, R.E. & T. Masuda (2003). Culture and point of view. Proceedings of the National Academy of Science 100, 11163-70. https://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.1934527100

Nofsinger, J.R. (2012). Household behavior and boom/bust cycles. Journal of Financial Stability 8, 161-173. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfs.2011.05.004

Norman, G., Sherbino, J., Dore, K., Wood, T., Young, M., Gaissmaier, W., Kreuger, S., Monteiro, S. (2014). The etiology of diagnostic errors: A controlled trial of system 1 versus system 2 reasoning. Academic Medicine 89(2), 277-284. https://doi.org/10.1097/ACM.0000000000000105

Novemsky, N. & D. Kahneman (2005). The boundaries of loss aversion. Journal of Marketing Research 42(2), 119-128. https://doi.org/10.1509/jmkr.42.2.119.62292

Odean, T. (1998). Volume, volatility, price and profit when all traders are above average. Journal of Finance 53(6), 1887-1934. https://doi.org/10.1111/0022-1082.00078

Odean, T. (1999). Do investors trade too much? The American Economic Review 89(5), 1279-1298. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.89.5.1279

Okun, A. (1981). Prices and quantities: A macro-economic analysis. The Brookings Institution.

Ortmann, A., G. Gigerenzer, B. Borges & D.G. Goldstein (2008). The recognition heuristic: A fast and frugal way to investment choice? In C.R. Plott & V.L. Smith (eds.) Handbook of experimental economics results: vol 1, Handbooks in Economics 28, 993–1003. https://doi.org/10.1016/S1574-0722(07)00107-2

Ottaviani, M. & P. Sorensen (2007). The favorite-longshot bias: An overview of the main explanations. In D. Hausch & W. Ziemba (eds.) Efficiency of Sports and Betting Markets, Elsevier: Handbook in Finance Series.

Pacheco, J. (2012). The social contagion model: Exploring the role of public opinion on the diffusion of antismoking legislation across the American States. The Journal of Politics 74(1), 187-202. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0022381611001241

Pachur, T. & M. Galesic (2013). Strategy selection in risky choice: The impact of numeracy, affect, and cross-cultural differences. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making 26, 260-271. https://doi.org/10.1002/bdm.1757

Page, L. & R.T. Clemen (2013). Do prediction markets produce well-calibrated probability forecasts? The Economic Journal 123, 491-513. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-0297.2012.02561.x

Pan, C. & M. Statman (2010). Beyond risk tolerance: Regret, overconfidence and other investor propensities. SCU Leavey School of Business, Research Paper No. 10-05.

Pennycook, G., D. Trippas, S.J. Handley & V.A. Thompson (2014). Base rates: Both neglected and intuitive. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Learning, Memory and Cognition 40(2), 544-554. https://doi.org/10.1037/a0034887

Peón, D., M. Antelo & A. Calvo (2015). A dynamic behavioral model of the credit boom. Journal of Economic Issues 49(4), 1077-99. https://doi.org/10.1080/00213624.2015.1105043

Plous, S. (1993). The Psychology of Judgment and Decision Making. McGraw-Hill.

Polman, E. (2012). Self-other decision making and loss aversion. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 119, 141-150. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.obhdp.2012.06.005

Prendergast, C. & L. Stole (1996). Impetuous youngsters and jaded old-timers: Acquiring a reputation for learning. Journal of Political Economy 104, 1105–34. https://doi.org/10.1086/262055

Rabin, M. (1998). Psychology and Economics. Journal of Economic Literature 36(1), 11-46.

Rabin, M. (2000). Risk aversion and expected-utility theory: A calibration theorem. Econometrica 68(5), 1281-92. https://doi.org/10.1111/1468-0262.00158

Rabin, M. (2002). Inference by believers in the Law of Small Numbers. Quarterly Journal of Economics 117, 775-816. https://doi.org/10.1162/003355302760193896

Rabin, M. & D. Vayanos (2010). The gambler's and hot-hand fallacies: Theory and applications. Review of Economic Studies 77(2), 730-778. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-937X.2009.00582.x

Rabin, M. & J. Schrag (1999). First impressions matter: A model of confirmatory bias. Quarterly Journal of Economics 114(1), 37-82. https://doi.org/10.1162/003355399555945

Rapp, A., L.S. Beitelspacher, D. Grewal & D.E. Hughes (2013). Understanding social media effects across seller, retailer, and consumer interactions. Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science 41, 547-566. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11747-013-0326-9

Ratner, R.K., Soman, D., Zauberman, G., Ariely, D., et al.(2008). How behavioral decision research can enhance consumer welfare: From freedom of choice to paternalistic intervention. Marketing Letters 19, 383-397. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11002-008-9044-3

Read, D., G. Loewenstein and M. Rabin (1999). Choice bracketing. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 19, 171-197. https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1007879411489

Richins, M.L. (1991). Comparison and the idealized images of advertising. Journal of Consumer Research 18(1), 71-83. https://doi.org/10.1086/209242

Rieger, M.O. (2012). Why do investors buy bad financial products? Probability misestimation and preferences in financial investment decision. Journal of Behavioral Finance 13(2), 108-118. https://doi.org/10.1080/15427560.2012.680991

Roca, M., R.M. Hogarth & J. Maule (2006). Ambiguity seeking as a result of the status quo bias. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 32(3), 175-194. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11166-006-9518-8

Roese, N.J. & K.D. Vohs (2012). Hindsight bias. Perspectives on Psychological Science 7(5), 411-426. https://doi.org/10.1177/1745691612454303

Rooderkerk, R.P., H.J. van Heerde & T.H.A. Bijmolt (2011). Incorporating context effects into a choice model. Journal of Marketing Research 48, 767-780. https://doi.org/10.1509/jmkr.48.4.767

Rubin, J. (2014). Centralized institutions and cascades. Journal of Comparative Economics 42, 340-357. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jce.2013.11.002

Sahi, S.K., A.P. Arora & N. Dhameja (2013). An exploratory inquiry into the psychological biases in financial investment behavior. Journal of Behavioral Finance 14(2), 94-103. https://doi.org/10.1080/15427560.2013.790387

Samuelson, W. & R. Zeckhauser (1988). Status quo bias in decision making. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 1(1), 7-59. https://doi.org/10.1007/BF00055564

Scheinkman, J.A. & W. Xiong (2003). Overconfidence and speculative bubbles. Journal of Political Economy 111(6), 1183-1219. https://doi.org/10.1086/378531

Schlüter, A. & B. Vollan (2015). Flowers and an honour box: Evidence on framing effects. Journal of Behavioral and Experimental Economics 57, 186-199. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.socec.2014.10.002

Schmidt, U. & H. Zank (2012). A genuine foundation for prospect theory. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 45, 97-113. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11166-012-9150-8

Schooler, L.J. & R. Hertwig (2005). How forgetting aids heuristic inference. Psychological Review 112, 610-628. https://doi.org/10.1037/0033-295X.112.3.610

Schwager, S. & K. Rothermund (2013). Motivation and affective processing biases in risky decision making: A counter-regulation account. Journal of Economic Psychology 38, 111-126. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.joep.2012.08.005

Schwikert, S.R. & T. Curran (2014). Familiarity and recollection in heuristic decision making. Journal of Experimental Psychology 143(6), 2341-65. https://doi.org/10.1037/xge0000024

Sen, A. (1995). Moral codes and economic success. In C.S. Brittan & A. Hamlin (eds.) Market Capitalism and Moral Values, Brookfield, Aldershot.

Shafir, E. & R.H. Thaler (2006). Invest now, drink later, spend never: The mental accounting of delayed consumption. Journal of Economic Psychology 27, 694-712. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.joep.2006.05.008

Shefrin, H. (2000). Beyond Greed and Fear: Understanding Behavioral Finance and the Psychology of Investing. Oxford University Press, second edition (2002).

Shefrin, H. (2006). Behavioral Corporate Finance. McGraw-Hill.

Shefrin, H. & E.M. Cervellati (2011). BP's failure to debias: Underscoring the importance of behavioral corporate finance. Quarterly Journal of Finance 1(1), 127-168. https://doi.org/10.1142/S2010139211000043

Shefrin, H. & M. Statman (1985). The disposition to sell winners too early and ride losers too long: Theory and evidence. Journal of Finance 40, 777-790. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.1985.tb05002.x

Shefrin, H. & M. Statman (2000). Behavioral portfolio theory. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 35(2), 127-151. https://doi.org/10.2307/2676187

Sherif, M. (1937). An experimental approach to the study of attitudes. Sociometry 1, 90-98. https://doi.org/10.2307/2785261

Shiller, R.J. (1984). Stock prices and social dynamics. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 457-498. https://doi.org/10.2307/2534436

Shiller, R.J. (2000a). Human behavior and the efficiency of the financial system. In B. Taylor & M. Woodfood (eds.), Handbook of Macroeconomics, Amsterdam: North Holland.

Shiller, R.J. (2000b). Irrational exuberance. Princeton University Press.

Shiller, R.J. (2003). From efficient market theory to behavioral finance. Journal of Economic Perspectives 17(1), 83-104. https://doi.org/10.1257/089533003321164967

Shin, H.S. (1992). Prices of state contingent claims with insider traders, and the favorite-longshot bias. The Economic Journal 102(411), 426-435. https://doi.org/10.2307/2234526

Shleifer, A. (2000). Inefficient Markets: An Introduction to Behavioral Finance. Oxford University Press. https://doi.org/10.1093/0198292279.001.0001

Shleifer, A. (2004). Does competition destroy ethical behavior? American Economic Association Papers and Proceedings 94(2), 414-418. https://doi.org/10.1257/0002828041301498

Slovic, P., M.L. Finucane, E. Peters & D.G. MacGregor (2002). The affect heuristic. In T. Gilovich, D. Griffin & D. Kahneman, eds., Heuristics and Biases: The Psychology of Intuitive Judgment, Cambridge University Press, 397-420. https://doi.org/10.1017/cbo9780511808098.025

Statman, M. (1999). Behavioral finance: Past battles, future engagements. Financial Analysts Journal 55(6), 18-27. https://doi.org/10.2469/faj.v55.n6.2311

Statman, M. & J.A. Weng (2010). Investment across cultures: Financial Attitudes of Chinese-Americans. Journal of Investment Consulting 11(1), 37-44.

Stevens, J.R. (2016). Intertemporal similarity: Discounting as a last resort. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making 29, 12-24. https://doi.org/10.1002/bdm.1870

Stöckl, T., J. Huber, M. Kirchler & F. Lindner (2015). Hot hand and gambler's fallacy in teams: Evidence from investment experiments. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 117, 327-339. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jebo.2015.07.004

Stulz, R.M. & R. Williamson (2003). Culture, openness, and finance. Journal of Financial Economics 70(3), 313-349. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0304-405X(03)00173-9

Suetens, S. & J.-R. Tyran (2012). The gambler's fallacy and gender. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 83, 118-124. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jebo.2011.06.017

Sul, S., J. Kim & I. Choi (2013). Subjective well-being and hedonic editing: How happy people maximize joint outcomes of loss and gain. Journal of Happiness Studies 14, 1409-1430. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10902-012-9379-6

Taylor, M.Z., & S. Wilson (2012). Does culture still matter? The effects of individualism on national innovation rates. Journal of Business Venturing 27, 234-247. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbusvent.2010.10.001

Thaler, R.H. (1983). Illusions and mirages in public policy. Public Interest 73, 60-74. Reprinted in H. Arkes & K. Hammond (eds.), Judgment and Decision Making: An Interdisciplinary Reader, Cambridge University Press.

Thaler, R.H. (1985). Mental accounting and consumer choice. Marketing Science 4(3), 199-214. https://doi.org/10.1287/mksc.4.3.199

Thaler, R.H. (1999). Mental accounting matters. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making 12(3), 183-206. https://doi.org/10.1002/(SICI)1099-0771(199909)12:3<183::AID-BDM318>3.0.CO;2-F

Thaler, R.H. (2008). Mental accounting and consumer choice: Anatomy of a failure. Marketing Science 27(1), 12-14. https://doi.org/10.1287/mksc.1070.0348

Thaler, R.H. & E.J. Johnson (1990). Gambling with the house money and trying to break even: The effects of prior outcomes on risky choice. Management Science 36(6), 643-660. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.36.6.643

Thaler, R.H. & H.M. Shefrin (1981). An economic theory of self-control. Journal of Political Economy 89(2), 392-406. https://doi.org/10.1086/260971

Thaler, R.H., A. Tversky, D. Kahneman & A. Schwartz (1997). The effect of myopia and loss aversion on risk: Taking an experimental test. Quarterly Journal of Economics 112(2), 646-661. https://doi.org/10.1162/003355397555226

Thaler, R.H., Sunstein, C.R. (2003). Behavioral economics, public policy, and paternalism: libertarian paternalism. American Economic Review 93(2), 175–179. https://doi.org/10.1257/000282803321947001

Trivers, R.L. (1971). The evolution of reciprocal altruism. Quarterly Review of Biology 46, 35-57. https://doi.org/10.1086/406755

Troye, S.V. & M. Supphellen (2012). Consumer participation in coproduction: "I made it myself" effects on consumers' sensory perceptions and evaluations of outcome and input product. Journal of Marketing 76, 33-46. https://doi.org/10.1509/jm.10.0205

Tsetsos, K., N. Chater & M. Usher (2012). Salience driven value integration explains decision biases and preference reversal. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America 109(24), 9659-64. https://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.1119569109

Tversky, A. & D. Kahneman (1971). The belief in the law of small numbers. Psychological Bulletin 76(2), 105-110. https://doi.org/10.1037/h0031322

Tversky, A. & D. Kahneman (1973). Availability: A heuristic for judging frequency and probability. Cognitive Psychology 5(2), 207-232. Reprinted in D. Kahneman, P. Slovic & A. Tversky (1982), Judgment under uncertainty: Heuristics and biases, Cambridge University Press.

Tversky, A. & D. Kahneman (1974). Judgment under uncertainty: Heuristics and biases. Science 185(4157), 1124-31. https://doi.org/10.1126/science.185.4157.1124

Tversky, A. & D. Kahneman (1981). The framing of decisions and the psychology of choice. Science 211(4481), 453-458. https://doi.org/10.1126/science.7455683

Tversky, A. & D. Kahneman (1982a). Evidential impact of base rates. In D. Kahneman, P. Slovic and A. Tversky, Judgment under uncertainty: Heuristics and biases, Cambridge University Press. https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511809477.011

Tversky, A. & D. Kahneman (1982b). Judgments of and by representativeness. In D. Kahneman, P. Slovic & A. Tversky, Judgment under uncertainty: Heuristics and biases, Cambridge University Press. https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511809477.007

Tversky, A. & D. Kahneman (1983). Extension versus intuitive reasoning: The conjunction fallacy in probability judgment. Psychological Review 90(4), 293-315. https://doi.org/10.1037/0033-295X.90.4.293

Tversky, A. & D. Kahneman (1986). Rational choice and the framing of decisions. The Journal of Business 59(S4), S251-S278. https://doi.org/10.1086/296365

Tversky, A. & D. Kahneman (1991). Loss aversion in riskless choice: A reference-dependent model. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 106(4), 1039-61. https://doi.org/10.2307/2937956

Tversky, A. & D. Kahneman (1992). Advances in prospect theory: Cumulative representation of uncertainty. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 5(4), 297-323. https://doi.org/10.1007/BF00122574

Tversky, A. & I. Simonson (1993). Context-dependent preferences. Management Science 39(10), 1179-89. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.39.10.1179

Weiner, B. (1985). An attributional theory of achievement motivation and emotion. Psychological Review 92, 548–573. https://doi.org/10.1037/0033-295X.92.4.548

Wu, J. (2015). Helpful laymen in informational cascades. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 116, 407-415. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jebo.2015.05.002

Zeisberger, S., D. Vrecko & T. Langer (2015). Measuring time stability of prospect theory preferences. Theory and Decision 72, 359-386. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11238-010-9234-3